Mardi Gris

Par Gilles Moëc, AXA Group Chief Economist et Head of AXA IM Research

  • Après les données subjectives, les données objectives commencent également à indiquer un scénario de stagflation aux États-Unis
  • Les droits de douane de 25 % sur les voitures sont un avant-goût de ce qui pourrait arriver mardi avec les « droits de douane réciproques »
  • Jusqu'à présent, la réaction du marché obligataire au changement fiscal allemand est cohérente avec un espace plus large fiscal pour le pays

Ce mardi, la publication des « tarifs réciproques » américains annoncera la généralisation de la guerre commerciale. Pourtant, on peut déjà voir les signes d'un scénario de stagflation pour l'économie américaine émerger avec, pour la première fois la semaine dernière, des « données concrètes » et pas seulement le sentiment qui sont touchés. La forte révision à la hausse des anticipations de prix des consommateurs les pousse à fermer leur porte-monnaie. Après la publication des chiffres des dépenses personnelles pour février, l'estimation Nowcast de la Fed d'Atlanta pour le PIB du premier trimestre s'établit à -0,5 %. La taxe de 25 % sur les voitures et les pièces automobiles pourrait à elle seule faire grimper l'inflation de base américaine de 0,6 % à 0,7 %. Ce choc pourrait être de courte durée, mais les conditions du marché du travail pourraient le rendre plus persistant, et nous gardons un œil sur l'autre choc négatif du côté de l'offre qui s'apprête à frapper les États-Unis : selon les données de la Border Protection, la répression de l'immigration entraîne déjà une très forte baisse des entrées. Cela pourrait maintenir la croissance des salaires à un niveau élevé même si la création d'emplois commence à vaciller.

Pour les Européens, les droits de douane sur les voitures donnent un avant-goût de ce qui les attend mardi. Compte tenu de la sensibilité particulière de l'Allemagne aux exportations automobiles, cela valide la nouvelle approche politique en Allemagne, qui met l'accent sur la relance des dépenses intérieures. Pourtant, à court terme, la douleur risque d'être intense. Les représailles probables de l'UE, très probablement via l'instrument de coercition anti-contrebande conçu en 2023, feront partie de l'équation. Les entreprises et les consommateurs européens devront faire face à l'incertitude quant au niveau final des « droits de douane réciproques » américains, car les négociations prendront du temps, tout en étant incertains de l'impact qu'ils auront sur leur propre économie étant donné la large fourchette d'estimations de l'élasticité des prix, ainsi que de l'effet de toute contre-mesure que l'UE pourrait prendre. C'est beaucoup à gérer.

Nous extrapolons la réaction du marché obligataire jusqu'à présent au changement de politique budgétaire en Allemagne pour étudier comment les conditions de viabilité budgétaire pourraient évoluer dans la zone euro. Pour l'Allemagne, la marge de manœuvre budgétaire s'élargirait - la relance budgétaire serait ainsi autofinancée - car le gain probable de la croissance nominale tendancielle dépasse de loin la hausse des rendements à long terme. Il n'en va pas de même pour la France ou l'Italie. Cela illustre une fois de plus la nécessité d'une plus grande émetteurion conjointe en Europe.

More hints at stagflation in the US

As much as we want to control our confirmation bias, evidence for – or at least hints at – stagflation continues to mount in the US, and this time it crossed the boundary between “soft” and “hard data.” The inflation-adjusted personal consumption number for February was key for the market. The January plunge (-0.5% mom in the first estimate) could easily be explained away by weather conditions. A “mechanical rebound” would ensue. Still, consensus for February had taken on board some impact from the recent deterioration in consumer confidence, with expectations of only a 0.3% gain, not a full offset then. The actual number came out even lower, at a meagre 0.1% (with a downward revision to -0.6% of the January reading). On a three-month annualised basis, US private consumption grew by only 0.2%, the worst result since December 2022 (see Exhibit 1). The Atlanta Fed Nowcast now corrects for the massive imports of physical gold which had artificially taken down their GDP estimate, but after the data releases from last week, their figure remains negative for Q1, at -0.5%.

Exhibit 1 – Ooops, it’s going down!
Exhibit 1 – Ooops, it’s going down!
Exhibit 2 – Inflation momentum up
Exhibit 2 – Inflation momentum up

Inflation allergy is more than a sentiment now, affecting actual spending decisions. The Federal Reserve (Fed)’s favourite gauge of inflation, core Personal Consumption Expenditures (PCE), also came out on the wrong side of consensus in February, rising 0.4% mom while the market was expecting 0.3%, unchanged from January. With more “accidents” along the way than the Consumer Price Index (CPI) measure, core PCE has quite clearly taken off from its summer 2024 lull (see Exhibit 2).

In such an environment, a trade war looks even more adventurous. Yet, even before the “reciprocal numbers” are released this week, the White House announced another sectoral tariff hike, with the 25% additional levy on cars, enforceable on April 2 for finished products, and from May onward on parts, thus further fuelling consumers’ fears on the inflation outlook. According to the White House’s own “Factsheet” accompanying the new Executive Order, imported cars account for about 50% of total car sales in the US, while the “import content” of cars manufactured in the US stands between 40 and 50%. The overall effect of the tariff hike on US domestic car prices is thus likely to be very significant, even if margins will absorb some of it.

The “budget lab” of Yale University estimates that overall, new cars’ prices in the US could rise by 13.5% (see link here). We would expect some spillover to used ones (which the Yale study does not take in consideration). Indeed, beyond the direct “price channel,” production disruption could emerge. In the short-run, US carmakers and car-importers will try to offload their inventories, but as they try to chase the lowest “tariff intensity” of their production lines, carmakers may face delays in supplying new vehicles, resulting in demand diversion towards used cars. Such pattern was observed when the economy emerged from the pandemic, with massive impacts on overall inflation (see Exhibit 3). Since new and used cars together account for 5% of the weights of the core CPI index, a hike of 13.5% would lift core inflation by 0.6-0,7%. The “transitory disturbance” in the US economy which the White House is now warning about may be quite significant if the car tariffs alone can visibly raise overall inflation.

 

Exhibit 3 – Cars matter for overall price dynamics sometimes
Exhibit 3 – Cars matter for overall price dynamics sometimes

Of course, we need to contemplate the other side of the equation: the possibility to see a significant increase in foreign investments in the US to circumvent tariffs (but only partly, because they would still need to source at least some parts from outside), lifting aggregate domestic capex and thus offsetting the adverse effect on consumption. The announcement by Hyundai that it will invest USD21bn in the years ahead in the US to produce steel and cars came at the right time for the White House. Still, this effect needs to be balanced against the deterioration in profits which the hike will trigger for US carmakers, which will make their investment effort more difficult (General Motors and Ford invest together roughly USD 20bn annually). ​

We also need to take into consideration the possibility that the Fed accommodates the shock. The tariffs’ impact should take the shape of a one-off price level shock – a “transitory” effect to re-use the word exhumed by Jay Powell two weeks ago. Transitory inflation has a nasty habit of turning persistent, but it takes specific conditions for this. The supply-side shock of the post-Covid reopening had a persistent price effect because pent-up demand could rely on massive cash reserves forcibly accumulated during the lockdowns and lingering fiscal support. If indeed US households continue to respond to the return of price pressure by closing their wallets, as they have been doing since the beginning of this year, the shock should be short-lived – at the cost of significant GDP growth impairment. Yet, the tariff effect is going to combine with another negative supply-side shock: the rapid decline in immigration.

According to the US Border Protection statistics (link here), in the first two months of 2025 their officers have made 110,000 “encounters” (i.e. came into contact with would-be immigrants) against nearly 500,000 in the corresponding period of 2024 and 425,000 in 2023. Deterrence seems to be working. While this down the line also impacts GDP adversely, it could add to US pressure on wages, possibly on a lasting basis. The Fed asserts that the US labour market is currently broadly balanced, neither adding nor subtracting to inflationary pressure. If job creation starts decelerating in earnest – which for now has not happened – the FOMC will still need to take on board the decline in labour supply to gauge the chances inflation duly falls after the one-off effect of the tariffs fade. In our view, while the Fed may be forced to resume cutting earlier than we thought until recently, this will have to be a reactive move – coming after the damage materialises – rather than a pro-active one.

More uncertainty within uncertainty

Even before the EU “number” is disclosed, the White House’s decision on cars last week is making one clear European victim, Germany, which accounts for three quarters of the cars shipped to the US from the EU. German car exports to the US stood in 2024 at EUR34bn, hence 0.8% of GDP. Given the high import content of cars, the “true” figure in terms of macroeconomic effect is closer to 0.5% - which by the way suggests that quite some pain will be felt in Central and Eastern European countries where the bulk of suppliers of German carmakers are located. If the price elasticity is unitary – a 1% price increase triggers a 1% decline in volume – the direct effect on GDP of a 25% tariff hike on cars would be visible, but not “crushing”. Unfortunately, this assumption is a strong one.

There is a profuse academic literature on estimates of “Armington elasticities,” which measure the degree of substitution in demand between similar products produced in different countries. A meta-analysis of existing literature from 2020 (see link here) found a range of 2.5 to 5.1, with a median of 3.8. Illustratively, if one applies this median to the current shock, the near entirety of German car exports to the US would be wiped out (without absorption in margins). There is no strong reason to think car imports display a lower elasticity than the average. In a less comprehensive study of Armington elasticities, research from the US International Trade Commission (see link here) found for transport equipment in general a range between 2.2 and 7.6.

Since the “reciprocal tariffs” will usher in a negotiation phase, uncertainty will still be a key channel through which the trade war will affect growth in Europe, but the “hard” 25% tariff on cars – there does not seem to be room for negotiation on this one, at least for now - will give us a first taste of the impact transiting through the price channel, and it is likely to be already quite painful. ​

Sentiment is already low in the Euro area judging by the European Commission surveys released last week. True, business confidence in manufacturing edged up again in March – possibly reflecting some early impact of the fiscal announcements from the German government - but it remains markedly below its long-term average, while confidence in services continued to deteriorate (see Exhibit 4). Consumer confidence also dipper lower in March. Interestingly, inflation expectations have been going up sharply over the last few months, despite favourable developments in observed consumer prices. The prospect of European retaliations may not help on that front (see Exhibit 5).

Exhibit 4 – Business confidence lower in services
Exhibit 4 – Business confidence lower in services
Exhibit 5 – Worried consumers
Exhibit 5 – Worried consumers

In an interview last week, Mario Draghi urged Europeans not to focus on tariff retaliation but instead concentrate on their own pro-growth agenda. Indeed, in principle, Europeans could simply let the US tariffs be their own punishment, given the adverse effect they should have on growth and inflation over there. Why should the Europeans add their own negative supply shock – in the form of higher inflation triggered by tariffs on US products – to the already painful negative demand shock on their exports? Yet, noises from Brussels and European capitals point to a “muscular reaction.” There may be two rational explanations here. First, a game theory approach: the threat of retaliation can be an asset in the negotiation that the release of the “number” will trigger. Second, a political economy argument: retaliation would be another way to cement Europeans’ renewed readiness to unify politically.

The first wave of retaliation could be almost instantaneous since it merely entailed reactivating countermeasures launched during the first trade war which had been suspended, rather than properly terminated. To go further and respond to a more generalised trade war after April 2, the Anti Coercion Instrument (ACI) offers a wider array of possibilities for retaliation: beyond trade tariffs “proper,” its most relevant aspect lies in the option to restrict services access to the European market, especially in the tech realm. As we discussed in our “Bretton Woods 3.0” piece a month ago, the EU’s large bilateral surplus on trade in goods over the US does not put it in a great position to negotiate with the US a “tariff disarmament”, but the EU’s large bilateral deficit on trade in services is a reflection of how crucial the European market is for US tech: this is where the balance of power changes.

Yet, even if the ACI was designed in 2023 with a “rapid reaction” aspect in mind, due process is not absent. The European Commission first must examine the existence of a “coercion case” within 4 months. Importantly, the Commission does not need the coercion measures by a third country to be enforced before starting the process: mere “intentions” suffice. Then comes the determination phase, where the European Council takes the lead. Within 8 to 10 weeks, the Council needs to form an opinion on the case, at a qualified majority. The Commission then engages in consultations with the country accused of coercive measures against the EU collectively or individual member states. The implementation of the anti-coercive measures is supposed to come only in last resort.

While the examination phase is likely to be short – that the US is using trade tariffs to exert pressure on the EU is explicit in their own communication – the determination phase may take a bit of time. Indeed, while there seems to be a generic consensus across EU capitals around some sort of retaliation, the discussions are likely to be more complicated when precise measures are put on the table given member states’ differing sensitivities to the US own measures (e.g. cars for Germany, food, and luxury goods for France). In addition, it is highly likely that Washington will try to play EU members against each other by skewing the product distribution of their own tariffs across the various member states’ product specialisations.

In a way, the ACI process is a good fit for what the US is trying to achieve with the “reciprocal tariffs” in the sense that it explicitly provides for a negotiation phase. Yet, it also adds to general uncertainty. Indeed, European businesses – and consumers – need to contend with uncertainty around the final level of the US “reciprocal tariffs”, while being unsure about the impact they will have on their own economy given the wide elasticity range, as well as about the ​ ramifications of any counter-measures the EU could take. This is a lot to take, on top of existing domestic softness, fuelled by excess savings.

One – crucial – element still missing in the European response

Still, at least there is one “upside risk” for Europe which was still missing at the beginning of the year: the now very tangible German plan for defence and infrastructure spending, which could cushion some of the adverse effect of trade-related uncertainty. Still, we think that the EU response is quite imperfect because it opens asymmetries across member states.

The bond market has treated all big European signatures in roughly the same way since the fiscal shift in Germany: spreads have barely moved (c.5 bps across France, Italy and Spain), with absolute long-term interest rates moving up by c.35-40 bps homothetically (see Exhibit 6): the upward revision in German yields, fuelled by expectations of more Bund supply in the years ahead triggered a general re-assessment of yields across the Euro area without much discrimination across signatures, despite the fact that only Germany has announced a significant change in its fiscal trajectory. ​

In Exhibit 7, we transpose this market reaction to long-term fiscal sustainability conditions across the Euro area. Using a multiplier of 0.7 for infrastructure and 0.3 for defence, a very tangible acceleration in German nominal GDP “trend” growth by a full percentage point may even be conservative (we put “trend” between quotation marks because this would not necessarily mean that underlying labour and capital supply, as well as productivity, would accelerate). Under these assumptions, the fiscal space defined by the difference between nominal growth and interest rates would widen for Germany, if the c.40bps rise in 10-year Bund yields seen this month is the right “premium” on German funding costs. In other words, the fiscal shift could be self-financed in Germany. Nominal GDP growth would also rise a bit in France and Italy, because of the spillover from the tangible acceleration in demand from Germany, but even with some modest national defence efforts, we would be surprised to see “trend” GDP accelerate by more than a quarter-point (in the German case, it’s the infrastructure effort which dominates in the growth impact). This would leave sustainability conditions unchanged for these two countries, with Italy still forced to maintain high primary surpluses, which does not sit well with any additional military spending, while France would see no additional space appear.

Exhibit 6 – Homothetic upward yield revision
Exhibit 6 – Homothetic upward yield revision
Exhibit 7 – “Sustainability inequality” even higher now
Exhibit 7 – “Sustainability inequality” even higher now

This gets us back – again – to the need to go further on joint funding of the defence efforts. While the material effects would be slow to emerge, more ambition on this side of the European equation would come at the right time to shore up business and consumer sentiment in Europe when “peak uncertainty” and the first tangible real effects of the tariffs are just ahead.

Dominique Frantzen

Senior Marketing & Communication Manager, AXA IM Benelux

Jennifer Luca

Marketing & Communication Manager – BeLux, AXA IM

Serge Vanbockryck

Senior PR Consultant, Befirm

 

 

 

 

Share

Recevez des mises à jour par e-mail

En cliquant sur « S'abonner », je confirme avoir lu et accepté la Politique de confidentialité.

À propos de AXA IM

AXA Investment Managers (AXA IM) est un gestionnaire d’actifs de premier plan proposant une gamme d’opportunités d’investissement diversifiée dans les classes d’actifs traditionnelles et alternatives. Nous cherchons à diversifier et à faire fructifier nos portefeuilles, tout en offrant à nos clients de la valeur et des performances d’investissement sur le long terme.

AXA IM gère environ 869 milliards d’euros d’actifs*, dont 480 milliards d’euros intégrant des critères ESG, durables ou à impact**.

Notre raison d’être est d’agir en faveur du progrès humain en investissant dans ce qui compte. En tant que gestionnaire d’actifs responsable, nous nous sommes engagés à intégrer les considérations ESG dans nos activités, de la sélection des titres à nos actions et notre culture d’entreprise.

AXA IM emploie plus de 2 800 collaborateurs répartis dans 23 bureaux et 18 pays**. AXA IM fait partie du Groupe AXA, un leader mondial de l’assurance et de la gestion d’actifs.

*à fin septembre 2024, incluant les entités non consolidées.

** à fin décembre 2023.

Consultez notre site internet : axa-im.be | axa-im.lu

Suivez-nous sur X @AXAIM

Suivez-nous sur LinkedIn